Site icon Bamboos Consulting

Capital Allocation Methods

Capital allocation methods are used to estimate risk margins in the form of return on equity (ROE) measurements and targets from a top-down perspective. Actuarial risk theory views risk from a bottom-up perspective because it aims at modeling solvency. At a macro level, financial theory views capital as the equity capital supplied by investors.

Kulik

Capital allocation evolved in such context with a final reconciliation and theoretical equivalence of capital allocation and risk load methodologies. Solid asset allocation is the objective of any methodology; however, the effectiveness of a capital allocation methodology can only be evaluated within its intended perspective. Consider the followings:

The two main components of investment strategy are Strategic Asset Allocation (SAA) and Tactical Asset Allocation (TAA). SAA sets the long-term asset allocation for the portfolio while TAA adjusts the asset allocation to short-term considerations, such as risks and investment opportunities. Investment strategy also covers investment selection, to populate each asset class with appropriate investments, and risk management.

For example, the long-term investment objectives may be beating inflation and growing the portfolio by 2% per annum. The investment constraints are excluding bonds below investment grade and alternative investments. The investment strategy may thus include SAA that allocates the portfolio to asset classes that keep up with inflation (e.g. inflation-linked bonds) and asset classes that provide growth over the long term (e.g. equities). Commodities, whose value normally increases with inflation, are excluded due to the constraints that do not permit investing in alternative investments. The expected return of the asset allocation is 4.5% per annum (2.5% for inflation and 2% for real return). TAA tweaks the allocation between equities and bonds based on the stage in the economic cycle and the view on whether equities should outperform or underperform bonds over the short term. Investment selection picks the actual investments under each asset class (e.g. active or passive equities) and ensures that all bonds are above investment grade, as per the constraints. Risk management guides the portfolio to the investor’s risk tolerance. The required risk level is not too high (the return objectives are relatively conservative), while enough risk should be taken to achieve the objectives.

Capital allocation methods

Traditionally, Markovitz’s Modern Portfolio Theory established a formal risk/return framework for investment decision-making, asset selection, and portfolio management by defining investment risk in quantitative terms. However, the framework has been continuously criticized since its introduction; substantially, PMPT and research in Behavioral Finance (CPT) had pointed the way showing how to apply the PMPT to improve investment results and to upgrade the MPT principles to a new level of usefulness.

The central idea of the Risk Parity approach is that in a well-diversified portfolio all asset classes should have the same marginal contribution to the total risk of the portfolio. In this sense, a risk parity portfolio is an equally weighted portfolio. Additionally, the approach relies on accurate estimates of volatility which have been to shown to be relatively stable.

A risk-parity portfolio RP would have performed very well during the last 20 years with an annualized rate of return of 7.12%. This is roughly equal to the annualized rate of return on the 60/40 portfolio with a volatility that is 50% smaller than that of the 60/40 portfolio.

A Volatility-Weighted approach considers the weight of each asset class proportional to the inverse of its volatility. This approach is identical to the risk parity approach when we have only two assets and it will be the same as risk parity in the more general case if correlations between asset returns are the same. Both the volatility-weighted and the risk parity portfolios have much higher Sharpe ratios than the 10/50/40 portfolio; thus, if levered up to have the same volatility as the 10/50/40 portfolio, they will have higher mean return than the 10/50/40 portfolio.

Risk parity and volatility weighted effectively bridge the gap between two foundational concepts in modern finance: the belief in efficient markets, and Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT). That’s because a Risk Parity portfolio delivers the most efficient returns when investors have priced markets appropriately, such that major asset classes are expected to deliver returns in proportion to the amount of risk each contributes to the portfolio. Investors who do not fully understand risk parity strategies often are concerned that the strategy’s higher exposures to fixed income will cause it to underperform traditional portfolios with more equity exposures over the long run. This is only true in situations where investors cannot use leverage.

The Kelly’s Criterion is well known among gamblers and investors as a method for maximizing the returns one would expect to observe over long periods of betting or investing. Kelly’s Criterion can be used to calculate
optimal returns and can generate portfolios that are similar to results from the Mean Variance-model; moreover, it can be used in either discrete finance or continuous finance applications. Substantially, Kelly’s Criterion is used to guide an investor to take more risk when investments are winning and cut risk when investments’ returns are deteriorating; thus, Kelly’s Formula is used to calculate optimal capital allocation between different investments and the optimal leverage of a portfolio.

For long term compounders, the good properties dominate the bad properties of the Kelly criterion. But the bad properties may dampen the enthusiasm of naive prospective users of the Kelly criterion. The Kelly and fractional Kelly strategies are very useful if applied carefully with good data input and proper financial engineering risk control.

The Black-Litterman Model

In a search for a reasonable starting point for expected returns, Black and Litterman (1992), He and Litterman (1999), and Litterman (2003) explore several alternative forecasts concluding that most lead to extreme portfolios. Thus, their model uses “equilibrium” returns as a neutral starting point.

The Black-Litterman model uses a Bayesian approach to combine the subjective views of an investor regarding the expected returns of one or more assets with the market equilibrium vector of expected returns (the prior distribution) to form a new, mixed estimate of expected returns. The resulting new vector of returns (the posterior distribution), leads to intuitive portfolios with sensible portfolio weights. The model overcomes the problem of unintuitive, highly-concentrated portfolios, input-sensitivity, and estimation error maximization.

Conceptually, the Black-Litterman model is a complex, weighted average of the Implied Equilibrium Return Vector ( Π ) and the View Vector ( Q ), in which the relative weightings are a function of the scalar (τ ) and the uncertainty of the views ( Ω ). From a macro perspective, the new portfolio can be viewed as the sum of two portfolios, where Portfolio 1 is the original market capitalization-weighted portfolio, and Portfolio 2 is a series of long and short positions based on the views. Below are three sample views expressed using the format of Black and Litterman (1990):

The uncertainty of the views results in a random, unknown, independent, normally-distributed Error Term Vector (ε ) with a mean of 0 and covariance matrix Ω. Thus, a view has the form Q+ε . The variance of each error term (ω ), which is the absolute difference from the error term’s (ε ) expected value of 0, form Ω, the diagonal covariance matrix.

In order to assess how the confidence level of the views impacts the portfolio, it is possible to compare the vector of the weights of the market with the vector of the weights obtained assigning 100% to confidence levels. Between the two will be the vector of the weights derived with the given confidence levels.

References

E. Elton, M. Gruber, S. Brown, W. Goetzmann. (2007). Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis, 11th edition.

T. Idzorek (2005). A STEP-BY-STEP GUIDE TO THE BLACK-LITTERMAN MODEL Incorporating user-specified confidence levels.

H. Kazemi. An introduction to Risk Parity

Z. Peterson. Kelly’s Criterion in Portfolio Optimization: A Decoupled Problem

L. C. Mac Lean, E. O. Thorp, W. T. Ziemba (2010). Good and bad properties of the Kelly criterion

Quantra (2019). Quantitative Portfolio Management

Exit mobile version